November 30th, 2006, 9:21 pm
The basic definition of complete markets is if you have the same number of linearly independent securities and states of nature (or future states). If this does not hold, then you do not have complete markets. Thus, if your 5 risky assets are "pure" securities, that is, they pay a value of $1 in one state and zero in another state, and you do not have assets that payoff the same in the same state, then you need to have five states of nature to have a complete market. The risk-free security's return can be replicated by a linear combination of the five risky assets, so this security is redundant. For example, if you have asset1=[1 0 0 0 0], asset2=[0 1 0 0 0], ..., asset5=[0 0 0 0 1], then a risk-free security that paysoff [x x x x x] can be replicated by a linear combination of assets 1 through 5. However, one of the assumtions of the CAPM, if I remember correctly, is that investors have the same beliefs or expectations (or something like that). Hence, in order for this to happen, you must have (at least sufficiently) complete markets. To see why, if you do not have complete markets, then the introduction of a new security will change the portfolio mix of some investors (because some would prefer this new security and sell other securities that they own in order to attain their mean-variance efficient portfolio) and, consequently, the supply and demand of assets in the market will also change. This would then lead to a change in the price of the securities, and homogenous expectations will not be attained.