April 16th, 2011, 9:31 pm
QuoteOriginally posted by: dunrewppYour discussion expands my original problem. Of course the answer to a probability question depends on how much you know about a given situation. A particular perspective gives a corresponding probability answer for the same event. Different people will arrive at different probabilities for the same event depending on how much each knows about the situation probably leading to the event. In my original problem, there was little information given and that's all you've got to go by. With just that, what's your answer?In fact it's very easy to take your line of analysis and apply it to just any probability problem. All you need to do is just creatively spin words around possibilities that somehow might have been present in the probability problem but not accounted for.Here's an example of creatively spinning words around possibilities ....Suppose there is a box and inside it are only two balls of the same size, weight, and other physical characteristics, but one is red, the other blue. We shake the box wildly until one ball falls out. What is the probability that the red one falls out?We have had problems of this sort all the while. So, now let's spin words creatively: Well, we have not accounted for the possibility that the red ball might be glued to the bottom of the box and that no amount of violent shaking of the box would release it from the box. So, the answer to the question is 0, and not 1/2.QuoteOriginally posted by: Traden4AlphaThis question makes assumptions about the underlying process. For IID processes, the 1/e answer is right. But other processes have other answers................................My points remain that: the process that generates "rare events" matters and the process that generates vigilance of the rare event matters, too. Only in the case of IID do we get the 1/e result.I admit that I expanded the problem and yet any answer to a probability-style brainteaser must expand the problem by bringing in base-level knowledge of "rare events", notions of probability, and time-based event generator processes, etc.In the context of undergraduate probability problems, IID is the norm and 1/e is the answer. But should we consider IID to be the default if we are an advanced quant? Here I think we might consider at least two streams of thought in answering:First, what's interesting to me is that the history of games of chance is one of people working extremely hard to create the normally unnatural condition of IID. Gamblers, casinos, and casino regulators have worked hard to create a fair games in a world in which fair games are, in fact, not the norm (by accident or fraud). From an empirical standpoint most natural and economic rare events arise from a process that doesn't generate perfect IID over time. So if my default reasoning on the question assumes a natural and economic source of the event, the P≠1/e.Second, you are right that I've spun the words of the problem. And yet that is exactly the kind of behaviour one should expect from counter-parties, regulators, opposing lawyers, and politicians. If the rare event involves a pay-off or consequences to other stakeholders, then I must consider the potential for interference that hastens or retards that event or induces non-independent versions of that event (e.g., a rare bankruptcy leads to a spate of bank runs).If Wilmott's brainteaser forum is meant for lower-level quants being hired by less-thoughtful people, then the answerer should assume IID and say "1/e". But if the brainteaser is meant for creme-of-the-crop quants who are expected to innovate to find new ideas, respond to complex risks, and deal with a socio-legal-political environment found at the very top of the quant food chain, then they'd better have a better answer than "1/e." That answer might be as I've outlined (i.e., "it depends on the event generator and here some common alternatives") or it might be an empirical answer (i.e., "given positively autocorrelated volatility often observed in financial markets, then P<1/e") or it might be a game theoretic answer (i.e., "how much will I and others win/lose if I assume IID?") Perhaps the real brain teaser, for the prospective job candidate, is to judge the cleverness of the interviewer as well as the nature of the job and decide if they want the undergraduate probability solution or something much more sophisticated.